Which of the following professionals is most likely to have nonstandard work hours?

Which of the following professionals is most likely to have nonstandard work hours?

Show

  • Which of the following professionals is most likely to have nonstandard work hours?
    Access through your institution

Which of the following professionals is most likely to have nonstandard work hours?

Which of the following professionals is most likely to have nonstandard work hours?

Abstract

This study adopts a potential outcomes framework to explore how nonstandard schedules (i.e., employment during nights, evenings, and weekends) affect partnership quality (PQ). Competing theories of positive and negative selection are proposed based on the contention that there will be heterogeneous returns to partnerships from nonstandard schedules (in terms of penalties and benefits) that will depend on how and why partners have selected into these arrangements. Mahalanobis Distance Matching techniques are then employed to mimic blocked randomization, simulate potential outcomes and identify patterns of heterogeneous effects using a sample of 21,766 workers in co-resident partnerships included in the UK Household Longitudinal Study (2010–2017). Results indicate that after correcting for baseline selection, weekend work only negatively affects PQ for mothers, whilst nonstandard hours take their most negative effect on PQ when worked by women without children. Maternal nonstandard hour work, on the other hand, is shown to positively affect PQ. However, results suggest this positive effect may often be obscured by patterns of negative selection. That is, the mothers most commonly observed in nonstandard hours are in partnerships that stand to benefit the least. In contrast, consistent patterns of positive selection into both nonstandard days and hours are observed for men without children, demonstrating the centrality of bargaining power and household constraints for selection. Such findings highlight the need to consider complex and gendered processes of household and socioeconomic selection when studying the relationship between nonstandard schedules and outcomes relating to family cohesion.

Introduction

A large body of research conducted over the past few decades has explored how nonstandard schedules (i.e., employment during nights, evenings, and at weekends) affect partnership quality (hereafter, PQ). The overwhelming consensus is that, by engaging a worker in paid labor during periods of the day and week typically reserved for family life, nonstandard schedules can restrict his or her ability to participate fully in the roles and rhythms of a conjugal relationship. This, in turn, can have negative impacts on partnership cohesion and stability. Compelling evidence of this comes from studies linking nonstandard schedules to a higher risk of union dissolution and conflict (Davis et al., 2008; Kalil et al., 2010; Presser, 2000; White and Keith, 1990) and decreased partnership satisfaction (Maume and Sebastian, 2012; Presser, 2003).

However, despite their discordance with the traditional temporal organization of family life, findings on the effects of nonstandard schedules on PQ are not all negative. A second strand of research has documented that nonstandard schedules can be beneficial to partnerships if they represent a strategic choice by the household. Such was found, for example, in the case of dual-earner parents selecting into desynchronized schedules to more equally distribute childcare between partners (e.g., Begall et al., 2015; Täht and Mills, 2012). Other research has highlighted that nonstandard schedules can promote work-family balance if they come with a high degree of flexibility and predictability, one of the reasons individuals often self-select into these arrangements (e.g., Staines and Pleck, 1986).

In attempting to reconcile these two conflicting strands of findings – one highlighting the negative effects of nonstandard schedules on PQ, the other highlighting the positive impacts of these arrangements – it is important to acknowledge the many channels of selection underlying employment in nonstandard schedules. Work schedule arrangements like night, evening, and weekend work are far from randomly distributed across the population. Rather, entrance into these schedules is influenced by complex and competing preferences and constraints tied to characteristics of an individual's household situation and occupation – factors that are likely not independent of outcomes relating to family cohesion. Moreover, a distinction must be made between those who choose for a variety of reasons to work nonstandard schedules and those on whom these arrangements are imposed by the employer or the nature of the job. Failing to account for these selection mechanisms will produce biased and inconsistent findings and undermine the ability to draw conclusions on the causal effect of nonstandard schedules on PQ.

This study builds on previous research on the effects of nonstandard schedules on PQ by attempting to characterize and correct for these selection processes. Competing theories of positive and negative selection are proposed based on the contention that there will be heterogeneous returns to partnerships from nonstandard schedules (in terms of penalties and benefits) that will depend on how partners have selected into these arrangements. To test these assertions, a potential outcomes framework is adopted, and Mahalanobis Distance Matching techniques are employed on 2010–2016 UK Household Longitudinal Study data to simulate blocked randomization and reduce baseline selection biases. To identify patterns of heterogeneous treatment effects bias, I compare the effect of a nonstandard schedule on PQ amongst those who actually work such arrangements to the effect that would be observed if otherwise equivalent individuals in standard schedules instead worked nonstandard schedules. Analysis is oriented around two main questions. First, net of baseline selection biases, are nonstandard schedules associated with lower PQ for the worker and/or her partner as previous research would suggest? Second, is there evidence of positive or negative selection into these arrangements amongst men or women that could have biased previous results?

Section snippets

Positive selection

Following principles of the rational choice framework, one thesis is that individuals choose to enter a nonstandard schedule only when the expected utility is greater than the expected cost. This is consistent with Becker's (1965) theory of the allocation of time, where decisions within the home surrounding the timing of paid work are grounded in rational deliberations of utility maximization for the actor. Through this lens, individuals choose to engage in paid employment during periods of the

Data

To test these hypotheses, this study uses Waves 2 to 7 (2010–2016) of the UK Household Longitudinal Study (UKHLS). The UKHLS is the largest household panel dataset in Europe, providing a nationally representative probability sample of over 40,000 households in the UK. Given the extensive scope of the UKHLS questionnaire, several variables (including those of interest to the current study) are only measured every other wave of data collection. Consequently, Waves 2, 4, and 6 (collected between

Results

Fig. 1, Fig. 2 plot standardized mean differences (SMD) in the unmatched sample between nonstandard and standard hour and day workers, respectively; for a table of SMDs, see Appendix F. At first glance, one can see some prominent patterns that portend negative selection into nonstandard schedules. For example, relative to control subjects, those engaged in nonstandard hours and days occupy jobs with significantly lower occupational status (ISEI), tend to be in non-salaried positions with longer

Sensitivity analyses

Several covariates included in the matching matrix could plausibly be conceived as causally downstream from nonstandard schedules; thus, matching on these factors may have obscured a portion of the treatment effect. Appendix J presents plotted ATEs estimated from models where potential mediators have been omitted. These are separated into: (1) theorized mediators of a negative effect of nonstandard schedules on PQ (household income, job hours, and whether respondent works a second job); and (2)

Discussion

The current study adopted a potential outcomes framework to test whether the individuals most likely to select into nonstandard work schedules – based on their relative position within the multivariate space of measured confounders – differ not only in their baseline PQ but also in the size and direction of the partnership returns they receive from working these arrangements. Net of the confounding effects of occupational, self-, and socioeconomic selection, I explored first whether nonstandard

Funding

This research was supported by the European Research Council grants 615603 (SOCIOGENOME) and 835079 (CHRONO) in addition to Nuffield College, University of Oxford.

Acknowledgments

I am grateful for the constructive comments received from anonymous reviewers and the Editorial team. I also express gratitude to Melinda Mills, Christiaan Monden, Man Yee Kan, Kadri Täht, Laura Langner, and John Ermisch for providing helpful comments on earlier versions of this manuscript.

References (51)

  • et al.

    Non-standard work schedules, work–family conflict and parental well-being: a comparison of married and cohabiting unions

    Soc. Sci. Res.

    (2011)

  • J.E. Brand et al.

    Regression and matching estimates of the effects of elite college attendance on educational and career achievement

    Soc. Sci. Res.

    (2006)

  • P.R. Amato

    Alone Together: How Marriage in America Is Changing. Ebook Central

    (2009)

  • P.C. Austin

    An introduction to propensity score methods for reducing the effects of confounding in observational studies

    Multivar. Behav. Res.

    (2011)

  • G.S. Becker

    A theory of the allocation of time

    Econ. J.

    (1965)

  • K. Begall et al.

    Non-standard work schedules and childbearing in The Netherlands: a mixed-method couple analysis

    Soc. Forces

    (2015)

  • S.M. Bianchi

    Changing families, changing workplaces

    Future Child.

    (2011)

  • W. Bielby et al.

    Family ties: balancing commitments to work and family in dual earner households

    Am. Sociol. Rev.

    (1989)

  • J.E. Brand et al.

    Who benefits most from college? Evidence for negative selection in heterogeneous economic returns to higher education

    Am. Sociol. Rev.

    (2010)

  • R. Carriero et al.

    Do parents coordinate their work schedules? A comparison of Dutch, Flemish, and Italian dual-earner households

    Eur. Sociol. Rev.

    (2009)

  • R. Chait Barnett et al.

    Wives' shift work schedules and husbands' and wives' well-being in dual-earner couples with children: a within-couple analysis

    J. Fam. Issues

    (2008)

  • C.C. Clogg et al.

    Statistical methods for comparing regression coefficients between models

    Am. J. Sociol.

    (1995)

  • R.D. Conger et al.

    A family process model of economic hardship and adjustment of early adolescent boys

    Child Dev.

    (1992)

  • G. Costa et al.

    Circadian characteristics influencing interindividual differences in tolerance and adjustment to shiftwork

    Ergonomics

    (1989)

  • J. Dakin et al.

    Money doesn't buy happiness, but it helps: marital satisfaction, psychological distress, and demographic differences between low- and middle-income clinic couples

    Am. J. Fam. Ther.

    (2008)

  • K.D. Davis et al.

    Nonstandard work schedules, perceived family well‐being, and daily stressors

    J. Marriage Fam.

    (2008)

  • P.B. Doeringer et al.

    Internal Labor Markets and Manpower Analysis

    (1971)

  • L. Golden

    Flexible work schedules: which workers get them?

    Am. Behav. Sci.

    (2001)

  • D.S. Hamermesh

    Who works when? Evidence from the U.S. And Germany

    Natl. Bur. Econ. Res. Work. Pap. Ser.

    (1996)

  • J.R. Henly et al.

    Nonstandard work schedules: employer‐ and employee‐driven flexibility in retail jobs

    Soc. Serv. Rev.

    (2006)

  • S.J. Heymann et al.

    The impact of parental working conditions on school-age children: the case of evening work

    Community Work. Fam.

    (2001)

  • J.M. Hoem

    Educational gradients in divorce risks in Sweden in recent decades

    Popul. Stud.

    (1997)

  • A. Hosking et al.

    The effects of non-standard employment on work--family conflict

    J. Sociol.

    (2008)

  • A. Kalil et al.

    Nonstandard work and marital instability: evidence from the national longitudinal survey of youth

    J. Marriage Fam.

    (2010)

  • A.L. Kalleberg

    Good Jobs, Bad Jobs: the Rise of Polarized and Precarious Employment Systems in the United States, 1970s to 2000s

    (2011)

  • Cited by (3)

    View full text

    © 2019 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

    What is the difference between dual

    Definition. The term dual-earner couple refers to a cohabiting couple where both partners work in the labor market. The term dual-career couple refers to a dual-earner couple where both partners are pursuing a career, that is, both are committed to work and perhaps also to progression at work.

    Which of the following is an example of a two person single career quizlet?

    Which of the following is an example of a two-person single career? Lydia and Bennett are a working couple. Lydia works as an accountant, while Bennett runs a software company out of home.

    Which of the following best describes absolute poverty quizlet?

    Which of the following best describes absolute poverty? It refers to not having enough money to afford the basic necessities of life.

    Is a process of social and economic change caused by the reduction of industrial activity especially manufacturing?

    De-industrialization is a process of social and economic change caused by the removal or reduction of industrial capacity or activity in a country or region, especially of heavy industry or manufacturing industry.